Steve Keen – Can’t we all be Swabian Housewives?

There is probably no economic fallacy that is so difficult to correct than that of Swabian hausfrau economics (you can only spend what you have) having no relevance with regard to public finance.

Steve Keen is an Australian economic historian and author.

Steve will be holding a talk in our series “Economics beyond the Swabian hausfrau” on 30 January 2019 in Franz-Mehring-Platz 1, 10243 Berlin at 7 pm. You are invited to attend.

Angela Merkel made the Swabian housewife a byword for fiscal responsibility in 2008, when at the height of the financial crisis, she ruled out using tax cuts to stimulate the German economy, saying that “we should ask a Swabian housewife: in the long run, you cannot live beyond your means”.  Swabian frugality has been an emblem of responsible fiscal management ever since.

So what’s the basic recipe of the Swabian housewife? It’s to spend less than you earn, and when you buy, to buy quality. We can all take the second lesson. But what about the first: is it possible for all of us to spend less than we earn? A simple thought experiment shows that no, it’s not possible.

Divide the EU into three sectors: Swabia, the rest of Germany, and the rest of the EU. Just to make the example simple, imagine that each has €1000 billion Euro cash, and that each spends €1000 billion per year on each of the other sectors, so that total spending per sector per year is €2 trillion.

How is this possible? Because a Euro can turn over several times a year: €1 in cash can yield €3 in income per year, if it turns over 3 times a year. Here I’m assuming that each Euro turns over twice a year, so that the “velocity of money”, as economists call it, is 2.

We can illustrate this in a table, where each row shows what a sector spends and who it spends it on, and each column shows expenditure and income for each individual sector. The entries on the diagonal of the table are spending by each sector (and shown as negative, because they reduce each sector’s bank balance), the other entries show which sector received the spending. Each row necessarily sums to zero.

  Swabia Rest of Germany Rest of the EU Sum
Swabia spending -2000 1000 1000 0
Rest of Germany 1000 -2000 1000 0
Rest of the EU 1000 1000 -2000 0
Sum 0 0 0 0

Total income in this example is €6 trillion (about half the EU’s actual income). This can be measured by adding up either all the expenditures (€2,000 trillion per year by each of three sectors) or all of the incomes (the same €2,000 trillion per year): you get exactly the same figure because, at the aggregate level, expenditure IS income: what you spend becomes income for someone else.

Because at the aggregate level, expenditure and income are identical, total savings are therefore zero. But the Swabian ambition is to save money. What if Swabia does that by spending €100 billion less on the rest of Germany, and €100 billion less on the rest of Europe as well? That way, so long as the rest of Germany and Europe keep doing what they were doing, Swabians will save €200 billion a year.

That’s great for Swabia, but what are the consequences for the rest of Germany, and the EU? As the next table shows, Swabia’s annual savings of €200 billion are precisely offset by dis-savings of €200 billion by the other two sectors. The Swabian savings of €200 billion per year cause the Rest of Germany and the Rest of the EU to dis-save by precisely as much.

  Swabia Rest of Germany Rest of the EU Sum
Swabia spending -1800 900 900 0
Rest of Germany 1000 -2000 1000 0
Rest of the EU 1000 1000 -2000 0
Sum 200 -100 -100 0

Of course, the Swabian reaction could be that this is due to the irresponsibility of the Rest of Germany and the EU: their income has fallen, so they should cut their expenditure to match.

What if they do that? What if, in response to Swabia deciding to spend €200 billion a year less, the Rest of Germany and the Rest of the EU do precisely the same? Then we end up with this situation:

  Swabia Rest of Germany Rest of the EU Sum
Swabia spending -1800 900 900 0
Rest of Germany 900 -1800 900 0
Rest of the EU 900 900 -1800 0
Sum 0 0 0 0

This is not quite the outcome the Swabian housewife would have expected: if each sector—Swabia, the Rest of Germany, and the Rest of the EU—tries to save €200 billion per year, the end result is not savings of €600 billion, but a reduction of GDP by €600 billion. Aggregate savings remain at zero.

This result appears paradoxical: surely the attempt to save money should result in money being saved? But the paradox can be easily resolved when you realise that, in this example, the amount of money is fixed: if one group (Swabians) acquire more of it, that necessarily has to reduce the amount that others hold by precisely as much. Since one person’s (or region’s or country’s) expenditure becomes another’s income, at the aggregate level, savings must be zero.

The real impact of this attempt to do the impossible—to save money at the aggregate level—has been to reduce how fast money turns over. In the initial example, it turned over twice a year, so that 3000 billion Euro generated 6000 billion Euro per year of income: each Euro is generating two Euros per year of income.

The end result, when all sectors attempt to save €200 billion per year, is an income of €5400. Each Euro is now generating only 1.8 Euros per year of income. The unintended outcome of trying to be frugal has been to make the Euro “lazier”—which is hardly the real ambition of the hard-working Swabian housewife.

This example is more than just hypothetical: it’s an explanation for why the Euro region has done so poorly, compared to other regions of the world that put less emphasis upon frugality.

The Swabian ambition of saving money was written into the Stability and Growth Pact, with its restrictions on government debt and deficits, but this Pact has delivered the opposite of its name. The USA, which has no comparable legislation, has grown faster and more smoothly than the Eurozone, even when the 2008 Financial Crisis—which originated in the USA—is taken into account. The USA’s growth rate since the inception of the Euro has been 2.1%, versus 1.4% for the Eurozone; and after the crisis, the USA has averaged growth of 1.5% per year, versus under 0.75% for the Eurozone.

The Eurozone’s performance has actually been worse after the Global Financial Crisis than before it, when a major reason for the Stability and Growth Pact was to make such crises less likely, and make Europe more resilient when they occurred. The outcome has been the opposite, because the ideas behind it, though clearly well-intentioned, were ill-founded. By setting an impossible goal of collectively saving money, the “Growth and Stability Pact” has brought stagnation and instability to Europe.

We are now seeing the political consequences of this, in the victory of anti-Euro parties in Italy, and in the protests in France by the Yellow Vest protests in France. Unless the roadblocks that the Stability and Growth Pact puts in the way of stability and growth, the political revolts against it are only going to get worse.

Be the first to comment

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published.


*